The (false) robot invasion

epa05338431 A visitor touches Pepper, a humanoid robot by Aldebaran Robotics and SoftBank Mobile, on display during the COMPUTEX, the largest computer show in Asia, in Taipei, Taiwan, 31 May 2016. The COMPUTEX computer show runs from 31 May to 04 June 2016 and gathers 1,602 exhibitors from 30 countries with 5,009 booths to display their latest products and to sign orders with foreign buyers.  EPA/RITCHIE B. TONGO
WASHINGTON

The robots are coming — but not in numbers that would imperil most Americans’ jobs. Few subjects have inspired as much hype as robots. Consider some sample headlines: “Robots and Computers Could Take Half Our Jobs within the Next 20 years,” “Robots Could Put Humans Out of Work by 2045,” “Why the Highest-Paid Doctors Are the Most Vulnerable to
Automation.”
Here’s why you should be sceptical, at least in the near term.
First, there’s little evidence that robots have yet had much effect on job creation in the current recovery. Since a low point of payroll jobs in February 2010, the economy has added 14 million jobs. These figures surely obscure countless thousands of jobs lost to automation, but that’s a normal part of a dynamic economy.
Second, the actual number of robots doesn’t suggest a huge impact either. In 2014, American firms installed 26,200 industrial robots, according to the International Federation of Robotics. That’s tiny compared with present payroll employment of 144 million, including 12 million manufacturing jobs. Even making generous assumptions about robots in stores or service jobs, the total remains modest. (In 2014, the U.S. industrial robotics market was the third largest, ranking behind China with 57,096 installations and Japan with 29,300.)
Finally, robots aren’t new. In his monumental study of U.S. innovation (“The Rise and Fall of American Growth”), economist Robert Gordon notes that General Motors introduced industrial robots in 1961. “By the mid-1990s, robots were welding automobile parts and replacing workers in the lung-killing environment of the automotive paint shop,” he writes. But the adoption of robots outside the manufacturing and wholesaling sectors will be a “long and gradual” process.
The alarmist headlines at the start of this article appeared in various publications and are quoted in an essay by Richard Freeman, a Harvard labor economist. As he notes, “most economists” (including Freeman) doubt the gloomy predictions of mass unemployment. True, robots enjoy some advantages over humans; they can work 24 hours a day and don’t have fringe benefits. Still, the economists have history on their side. It’s all happened before.
There is no conceptual difference between robots and earlier labour saving technologies, including the switch from steam power to electricity and the adoption of the
assembly line. Although innovation hurts some industries and workers, it helps others by inspiring new products or reducing prices. Low prices spurred demand for
both the Model-T and smartphones. Meanwhile, new satellite industries arise — say, cybersecurity now.
Finally, there’s inertia. Some innovation occurs slowly, because it encounters practical problems. Take driverless vehicles — self-propelled robots — which have received huge publicity. They are unlikely to become
widespread soon. Dozens of regulatory issues need to be settled. Nor is it clear what the demand for driverless vehicles will be.
Consider. An opinion survey by Brandon Schoettle and Michael Sivak at the University of Michigan found that only 16 percent of respondents wanted self-driving vehicles; 39 percent preferred “partially self-driving” and 46 percent wanted no “self-driving” features. Safety is one anxiety. Cost may be another. Presumably, car prices would be higher, reflecting the costs of software, sensors and electronics. Will drivers pay the premium, especially when today’s cars last longer than ever? (The average age of today’s vehicles is 11 years, up from five years in 1969, reports the Department of Transportation).
All these factors argue against the doomsday specter of robots creating mass unemployment. Of course, dramatic increases in the minimum wage will quicken the pace of
automation. More jobs will be lost.
Still, the real problem, suggests Harvard’s Freeman, is not jobs but wages. The added competition from robots will depress workers’ wages and salaries. This could happen, but it’s an open question and overlooks an important countervailing force. As baby boomers age and retire, growth in the labor force is slowing. Workers may become scarce, pushing up their wages.
— Washington Post Writers Group

ROBERT J. SAMUELSON
Robert Jacob Samuelson is a columnist for The
Washington Post, where he has written about business and economic issues since 1977, and is syndicated by the
Washington Post Writers Group

Leave a Reply

Send this to a friend