When I am trying to understand the macroeconomy, I often find myself resorting to one of my favorite sayings: All propositions about real interest rates are wrong.
For starters, let’s define the real interest rate, or more properly a term series of real interest rates. If the long rate is published at say 6%, that is the nominal long rate. The real interest rate adjusts that figure for inflation, so if inflation rates are 4%, the real long rate is 6% minus 4%, or 2%.
Almost everything beyond that is murky.
During the 1990s, a series of tax hikes and changes in federal spending trajectories reduced the US budget deficit. The goals were to restore fiscal prudence, lower real interest rates and boost private-sector investment. That all seemed to succeed, and economists went away confident that they understood not only real interest rates but also many other things.
Alas, we did not. Since the presidency of Bill Clinton, the US has run staggeringly large budget deficits, and racked up trillions in government debt, including most recently from the pandemic. Yet real interest rates have continued to fall, often reaching into negative territory, especially for short-term rates. Naïve theory predicted that they should rise.
The law of demand is one of the sacrosanct principles of economics: If the price of apples goes up, the demand for apples will go down. Yet when real interest rates go up, it is not obvious that the demand to invest goes down, even if the numbers are adjusted for possible reasons why real interest rates might have changed in the first place. This raises a profound question: If the law of demand doesn’t apply, how well do we understand investment and real interest rates at all?
The puzzles deepen. There was a longstanding debate in economics about whether the US Federal Reserve, using monetary policy, could affect real rates of interest. . Yet the effect is sufficiently small that there can be a plausible debate about whether, statistically speaking, it exists at all. These days, however, the real federal funds rate measures as below -4%, based on measures of core inflation. No one doubts that the monetary expansions of the Fed, which have brought much higher inflation, are a major factor behind that shift.
In other words, the Fed’s impact on real rates is far more potent now than in times past.
It gets worse yet. Most observers were not anticipating that expected short rates could fall and stay below -4%. Why hold those assets at all? I don’t have a good answer to that question.
Recently the term structure of interest rates has become inverted, by which it is meant that the short-term rates are higher than the long-term rates. Economists have debated for decades whether such a sign might be a good predictor of a recession. Yet the current data are ambiguous. So not only are real interest rates often hard to predict, but they themselves are not clear predictive signals on their own.
—Bloomberg